FEATURE
Open Access or Differential Pricing
for Journals: The Road Best Traveled?
by David Stern
Open access (OA) is becoming a reality, with new
cost models under development. The various cost models
will have serious short- and long-term implications
for libraries and dangerously impact the scholarly
communication network. I believe that the adoption
of the OA model for journals will create serious
instabilities within the existing scholarly publication
industry. OA, as a business model, is neither necessary
nor desirable. With or without the often-discussed
author charges approach, it would be almost impossible
to obtain the same amount of total revenue through
selected libraries as now exists from the much larger
base of library subscriptions. Tiered or differential
pricing (and services) among the existing subscribers
would be a far more logical approach to supporting
a modified scholarly journal distribution network.
WHY OPEN ACCESS IS EVEN ON THE TABLE The OA model now being explored and promoted by
selected publishers is actually the result of intentional
corporate misdirection. Originally, publishers used
this tactic in hopes of appealing to our altruistic
tendencies, thereby deflecting attention away from
unreasonably inflated prices [1]. The "more people
than ever have access" position was used to rationalize
high prices. This OA position was never proposed
as a viable alternative business model, and the publishers
that offered the OA rationale never wanted to actually
create a different pricing model. In retrospect,
this OA movement has become a danger to the very
people who used it as a diversionary tool.
OA has now been adopted primarily by selected prestigious
publishers and endorsed by certain start-up journal
publishers. Meanwhile, many of the traditional publishers
see this as a long-term danger that will significantly
reduce the number of organizations making up the
present revenue base. From a business point of view, OA creates serious
concerns. It reduces the stability of the system
without offering a viable substitute for the existing
revenue stream. A business analysis of the OA model
will demonstrate the flaws within the assumptions
and will revise the approach before it becomes a de
facto option. It is the responsibility of publishers,
librarians, serials agents, and authors/editors to
review this OA business model. This article will
attempt to place this review within the context of
both the current and future scholarly information
networks. It will compare OA possibilities with both
existing subscription models and alternative, revenue-generating
journal cost models. Until now, many of the conversations about OA journals
have resembled conflicting religious opinions rather
than evidence-based conversations. Great confusion
and emotion have been evident as people within the
industry run toward and away from this new paradigm
at meetings. Unfortunately, the ideas of author charges
and OA have become synonymous. The separation of
a general theory and a particular implementation
is the first problem that must be addressed when
discussing this new approach. In addition, serious
evaluation must be based upon long-term and seriously
analyzed business practices and economic realities. THE UNDERLYING INDUSTRY FACTS Often, the facts inherent in the journal publishing
industry are not clearly identified at the start
of the conversation. Here are a few of the key issues
to remember:
Peer-review is important and must be maintained for the scholarly system
to remain viable.
There is a real cost for peer review,
based upon the
required infrastructure.
There is a cost for distribution, both
in online and paper methods.
There is a cost for the online infrastructure
support (editing and archiving).
There will be costs for enhanced linking
options in the online environment.
There is degree of revenue redirection
in the present system for most publishers (commercial
profit and societies subsidizing member dues).
Technology makes possible less-expensive
peer-review and networking options.
It is now possible to create integrated
scholarly networks for peer review and for the
distribution of other materials (teaching tools,
electronic communities, etc).
Networks would be less expensive if they
were shared and unnecessarily redundant features
were removed.
Subject-based centers of excellence would
be logical and cost-effective network hubs.
These costs must be supported by participants
with a variety of interests and reasons for maintaining
this
information network.
Once all of these elements are taken into consideration
and a logical enhanced online network is planned
for subject communities, one must compare these possibilities
and realities to the business considerations of the
OA model. BUSINESS MODEL ASSUMPTIONS AND REALITIES Open access journals do not provide a significant
solution to current scholarly information distribution
concerns. While OA publication may seem like a great
idea at first, there are reasons why OA for journal
articles is not the right approach to distributing
scholarly information. First, there is a fatal flaw in the pricing model
of OA. Interest in maintaining the same support for
peer-reviewed material is not equal within the existing
revenue base. The majority of authors willing to
support some form of scholarly publication reside
in academia. However, many readers are located in
commercial organizations having little interest in
altruistic support if the information can be obtained
freely through OA. If possible, these readers will
simply drop direct support and expect additional
taxpayer dollars to subsidize this process. If OA
were adopted, the entire revenue stream would then
need to be channeled through far fewer institutionsrequiring
a much higher budget for academic libraries. Given
the current financial situation and existing allocation
patterns, plus the obviously outrageous inflation
and profit by commercial publishers, obtaining higher
budgets for academic institutions would be very difficult
to accomplish. Even if accomplished, it would not
correct the existing problems of commodity trading
within the academic publication world. It would merely
delay addressing the problem and shift more of the
problem to the individual taxpayers rather than to
the corporate world. Clearly, there would be a sharper
divide between the haves and have-nots over time
as taxpayers located in different research communities
supported such higher prices at differing levels. The initial flaw of creating a reduced revenue
stream based only upon production-centered vested
interest is even more problematic if revenue is also
based upon author charges. With OA, online journals
are available freely on the Internet to all libraries
without a subscription. Decisions to maintain paid
subscriptions will be based solely upon (1) a need
to maintain a paper copy, or (2) significant savings
obtained through reduced author charges. As few libraries
will feel the need to maintain paper archives, and
fewer will see any benefit from reduced author charges,
there will be far fewer libraries remaining as a
revenue base compared to the present revenue sources
from academic institutions. Only a few institutions
will generate enough author publications to see any
benefit. In addition, there are currently no existing
channels for blending joint revenue sources between
library funds and direct author funding. This would
be an auditor's nightmare to develop, is not desirable
by libraries or authors, nor is it necessary in order
to maintain a working revenue model. OA will result in far fewer commercial revenue
sources, and many lost academic library subscriptions.
The remaining libraries will be asked to cover the
entire revenue baseand this is simply not viable.
As a business model, the reliance on fewer vested
and altruistic supporters simply is not practical. In addition, OA would also mean the loss of existing
subsidies that support the maintenance and development
of long-term archives such as the JSTOR consortia.
OA would create a system more like HighWire, with
reliance upon annual subscriptions to support OA
infrastructures. There would once again be even greater
reliance on fewer annual contributors. As a business
model, the reliance on fewer vested and altruistic
supporters to maintain archiving is also not practical. In short:
OA based upon author charges. OA
based upon author charges will reduce the number
of subscriberscreating complex changes
in the budget processes and problems with maintaining
the existing revenue base.
OA without author charges. OA regardless
of author charges will still reduce the number
of subscriberscreating a serious problem
in maintaining the existing revenue base.
ECONOMIC EXAMPLES Nucleic Acids Research is one of the first
major titles to move to this OA modeland there
will be a significant reduction in support unless
(1) many libraries feel a burning need for paper,
and/or (2) there are many libraries that expect to
see and manage real savings from repeated author
charges. Even with such a prestigious title, this
seems to be a rash action reminiscent of the old Britannica OA
attempt. Even if it were to work for the prestigious NAR,
it certainly does not seem a viable model for the
many less-prestigious titles with far fewer authors
and institutions willing to support these less-valuable
entities. Publish-or-perish pressure supporting unaccountable
library expenditures can only reach down so far into
the existing and exploding titles.
Nucleic Acids Rqueues
Yale authors: 10 in 2002, 18 in 2003,
estimated 22 in 2004
Cost model of $1,500 per article (full
cost without license) = $33,000 for the year
$500 reduced institutional cost = $11,000
in author charges
Savings = $22,000
At first this looks like a good deal, but the current
Yale expenditure is only $2,855 for paper plus online
without the OA option. In purely economic terms, this model makes no sense
for Yale. Are libraries willing to shift the burden
to a few institutions, hoping these will find a way
to discover new money? Are there enough institutions
willing to pay based upon these "proposed" savings?
Under this model, an organization would need to publish
five articles to break even, and more than five to
see any "savings." How many organizations would fit
within that category? Not many, and not all of these
could afford such a price increase in order to subsidize
the rest of the world. Other Popular Offerings The following two well-known OA initiatives started
with entirely new journals. Without an existing subscription
base, a pricing model was developed that initiated
institutional fees as a supplement or alternative
to author charges. Both initiatives include differential
pricing models for the institutional membership fee.
Membership means that these organizations agree to
support the archival infrastructure for all previous
authors and memberships and for the rest of the world. Public Library of Science (PLoS) This initiative offers reduced author fees within
membership organizations. As an institutional member,
authors can publish at a 50 percent discount ($750)
on the $1,500 2004 publication fee. Depending upon
the number of papers published, this can become very
expensive; further, it would be impossible to project
costs and would require complex author payment support
mechanisms. Compared to subscription plans with known
annual costs and one-source payments, this does not
seem like a preferred method for both logistical
and budget planning reasons. The Public Library of Science journals are PLoS
Biology [www.plosbiology.org] and PLoS Medicine,
[www.plosmedicine.org].
BioMed Central This initiative has decided to charge no author
fees within membership organizations. As a benefit
of library membership, the $500 article processing
fee is waived for all articles published in one of
BMC's 60 peer-reviewed journals. In addition, articles
are immediately archived for permanent access in
PubMed Central by the U.S. National Library of Medicine,
which is part of the National Institutes of Health.
Membership means that these organizations may not
be supporting an archival infrastructure for all
previous authors and memberships if an outside archive
platform is trusted. At first, compared to traditional
subscription plans with known annual costs and one-source
payments, this does seem like a reasonable charging
method; however, there is still the issue
of significantly fewer organizations needing to pay,
as well as much higher charges for the author-based
organizations. This voluntary institution fee provides
an adequate charging mechanism, but the OA altruistic
vested interest contributor aspect still creates
a problem in maintaining a broad and viable revenue
stream compared to the current larger revenue base. Yale has additional information on BioMed Central
and how to publish in a BMC journal [www.med.yale.edu/library/new/biomedcentral.html].
Other Sample Journal Costs The following individual journal scenarios demonstrate
the real and projected costs of traditional and OA
modelsusing a "reasonable best guess" standard
cost-per-article value. Journal of Insect Science An inexpensive OA journal based within the University
of Arizona, with shared responsibilities among the
faculty and the library. Estimates from the staff
are $850/author per paper. There are no author charges
now.
Produced 25 articles in 6 months of 2004
50 articles per year @ $850/author = $42,500
if 20 libraries subscribe, the annual
cost for each is $2,125 per year
if 60 libraries subscribe, the annual
cost for each is $708 per year
if 120 libraries subscribe, the annual
cost for each is $354 per year
Clearly even a small and inexpensive journal is
much easier to maintain by a larger number of institutions.
This situation scales even more as the number of
titles is expanded and the journals become more expensive.
At $850, author charges would be outrageous for authors
from small organizations. Continued absorption of
these costs will need to be through either sharing
among many organizations or through one larger, centralized
funding source. Physical Review B An important and relatively inexpensive society
journal based upon impact factor and price-per-page.
We will
assume the same estimates of $850/author per paper.
497 articles for year 2003 @ $850/author
= $422,450
OA author charges: Yale authors: 17 in
2002, 18 in 2003, estimate 20 in 2004 = $17,000
The current Yale expenditure is only $8,740 for
paper plus online without the OA option.
if 20 libraries subscribe, annual cost
for each is $21,123 per year
if 60 libraries subscribe, annual cost
for each is $7,041 per year
if 120 libraries subscribe, annual cost
for each is $3,520 per year
if 200 libraries subscribe, annual cost
for each is $2,112 per year
Clearly, a large and inexpensive journal is much
easier to maintain by a larger number of institutions.
At $850, author charges would still be outrageous
for many organizations. As the OA costs are far higher
than current subscription costs or the proposed shared
cost, continued stable revenue will be best provided
through either sharing among many organizations or
through one larger, centralized funding source. DIFFERENTIAL PRICING Perhaps differential pricing might be a way to
adjust more fairly the costs across the existing
subscriber base. These differential pricing models
could be developed in relation either to the level
of access or types of customized services desired.
The American Physical Society, the publisher of Physical
Review B, already offers this type of tiered
pricing model based upon research level of the organization.
Other publishers use this model, and additional differential
pricing models base costs upon actual use. Using the same Physical Review B cost information
to develop a simple differential pricing model, let's
assume two rates: with 200 libraries at full rate
and 200 libraries at half-rate. This yields the following
numbers:
higher = 75 percent = 316,838 = $1,584
per library
half rate = 25 percent = 105,613 = $528
per library
This differential pricing model seems to be a far
more practical way to share journal costs without
endangering the entire scholarly distribution network.
Differential pricing creates a larger but fairer
revenue base, and a less expensive per-library model
than OA. Why would libraries willingly want to move
away from a model that includes many types of existing
and reasonable revenue support streams toward one
that is far more expensive and has questionable and
potentially flawed business assumptions? Moving to
an OA pricing model does not address or adjust the
problems created by commercial inflation. Changes
need to be made in order to develop a more powerful
and less-expensive scholarly distribution mechanism,
but OA does not seem to be a solution. THE REMAINING QUESTIONS Clearly, there are also unintended consequences
of accepting the OA model without significantly changing
the underlying peer-review and commercial aspects
of the existing journal publication system. It is
therefore time to ask a few questions about these
traditional publication features. First, are we happy with what exists? Do publishers
produce enough added value for their commercial surcharge?
Is the added value what users and librarians want
and/or need, and is it worth the cost? Technology
allows for significant changes in copy editing and
formatting, and these might change the expectations
and costs. To be an important factor, OA models must
adequately address these escalating costs for both
traditional offerings and new R&D options. In
terms of OA impact, it is likely that these improvements
will only be supported by those interested in having
their own published materials available, as opposed
to being supported by all participants interested
in enhanced navigation and distribution options.
OA seems to provide a great challenge in terms of
supporting revisions and enhancements to the existing
systems, as it separates and places in conflict the
interests in (1) least expensive publication costs
and (2) expensive enhanced discovery and delivery
options. Here are some other related questions: What are
the incremental add-on costs for an online distribution
system? What are the best ways to support the new
infrastructures, metadata, and enhanced linking options?
Is there benefit to having a variety of branded products,
or would users be better served with a standard set
of options under one basic interface style? How will
OA models handle these beyond-publication infrastructure
costs? In the differential pricing subscription model,
there could be add-on options for those interested
and willing to pay for premium services. If the questions
are about how publishers can generate revenue and
whether there are other, better pricing models, then
perhaps the differential pricing models offer a more
appropriate mechanism. These models utilize the new
technologies to provide a variety of customized services
that are now possible and desirable for different
user populations. Another issue needs to be considered: How does
OA affect the remaining journal package plans? Will
a move toward OA result in better long-term costs/benefits
for users and/or authors/editors? If the goal is
to provide the best cost for the dollar, OA seems
to significantly raise the cost to a few and reduce
the cost to manybut in the process, it endangers
the entire system. Package plans spread the cost
out across the researcher population, exactly the
opposite of the OA model. As we have seen before,
these two approaches are diametrically opposed, and
this entirely new approach to allocating support
revenue would create an impossible strain on the
few. The intention of package plans (for many librarians)
was to allow not just access to a broader range of
materials, but also to generate use statistics that
would eventually allow us to develop more accountable
use-based pricing models. This would, over time,
provide differential pricing based upon local populationsa
more fair distribution of costs. OA would allow for
gathering use statistics, but without the ability
to identify and allocate the appropriate and reasonable
shared infrastructure costs. While an OA model can
offer use-based analysis, it provides fewer possibilities
for influencing reductions in commercial distribution
costs based upon the findings. The incentive to reduce
costs for the few is far less powerful than the leverage
created by reducing the costs to many. There is one final question buried within the OA
charging model: Is it acceptable to include "hidden
altruistic" OA to the world automatically through
higher journal costsor is it better to offer
this OA subsidy as an obvious choice to taxpayers?
I suggest that the average person in a state with
serious researcher populations would not be happy
to discover that by accepting the proposed OA model,
they are unknowingly continuing to accept inflated
prices, they are absorbing much of the cost previously
paid by commercial firms, and they are heavily subsidizing
the world's existing commercial distribution method.
If the idea of OA is treated as a real cost/benefit
issue, it will be clear that the costs are higher
to the few and the benefits would go to the publishers
rather than to the community. Of course, this ignores a rather significant issue,
one that I will leave for another time: Library subscriptions
are still supporting a commercially controlled and
somewhat misdirected peer-review process in need
of serious revision. Quality control and distribution
can be handled in many less-expensive ways using
the latest technologies, but this will require significant
modifications of author, editor, and administrative
behaviors. EXTENDED SCHOLARLY NETWORK IS THE REAL GOAL Beyond the simple economic concerns, open access
to academic information should exist on a platform
and infrastructure providing more than just peer-reviewed
literature. More comprehensive OA networks should
develop, using redirected current commercial revenues,
and these networks should utilize new technologies
in order to create powerful integrated scholarly
networks. These centers of excellence can be discipline-based
scholarly platforms that handle all materials: peer-reviewed
journals, teaching materials, curriculum support
software, simulations, etc. Scholar networks are
springing up all over the Internet with little library
support or integration. This is where OA should be
focused, on support for the distribution of noncommercial
materials within these newly developed networks.
We need to maintain a fair and reduced revenue base
for publications, supplemented by redirected revenue
for innovative scholarly networks. Don't be misdirected
by talk of altruistic OA of journal literature. We
should be collaborators and players, redirecting
our efforts and resources into developing enhanced
scholarly networks, rather than discussing simplistic
and flawed economic models for maintaining the limited
and expensive journal distribution network of today. In summary, the open access publishing model is
not necessary, not desired by the key players, and
a real danger to the stability of the existing scholarly
publication network. As long as the publication of
journals remains commercially tied to the underlying
peer-review infrastructure, there will need to be
a large revenue stream, regardless of the actual
distribution mechanism. This expensive quality control
and distribution system will need to be supported
by a large population, and OA works in the opposite
direction by attempting to shift the support from
the large group of readers to the few information
producers. The OA process is not based upon a realistic
business model. Those with a vested academic interest
in producing and disseminating results do not have
the capital to subsidize the entire process. Those
with a need for the information for profit would
be exactly the readers that would no longer support
the infrastructure. An appeal to altruism will simply
not work, and the removal of corporate and less research
intensive support will be exactly the opposite of
what is required to make this system an enhanced
and more comprehensive scholarly network. Perhaps
differential pricing models would provide a much
better alternative for shared support of a revised
scholarly distribution network, composed of open
access for portions of the contents held within subject-based
centers of excellence information platforms. Open Access Readings Budapest Open Access Initiative FAQ [www.earlham.edu/~peters/fos/boaifaq.htm] ARL Framing the Issue site [www.arl.org/scomm/open_access/framing.html] The Open Archives Initiative (DLF, CNI,
NSF) Santa Fe Convention [www.openarchives.org/] Landmarks in the evolution of open access [www.earlham.edu/~peters/fos/timeline.htm] Directory of Open Access Journals (1096
journals) [www.doaj.org/] ARC demonstrationharvesting search engine [http://arc.cs.odu.edu/]
Public Library of Science (PLoS) [www.publiclibraryofscience.org/] arXiv (high energy physics with no peer
review) [http://arxiv.org/]
DSpace MIT Libraries and Hewlett-Packard (HP)
[www.dspace.org/]
Charleston Advisor special issue [www.charlestonco.com/features.cfm?id=151&type=me]
Reference
[1] Ewing, John H. Point of View article
"Open access to journals won't lower prices" Chronicle
of Higher Education October 1, 2004 [http://chronicle.com/weekly/v51/i06/06b02001.htm].
David Stern [david.e.stern@yale.edu]
is Director of Science Libraries and Information Services,
Kline Science Library, Yale University.
Comments? E-mail letters to the editor to marydee@infotoday.com.
|